Skip to main content

Finding the market equilibrium price and quantity

Finding the equilibrium price and quantity is perhaps one of the most common problems in an introduction to Microeconomics course, which is exactly what we are going to do in this post!

Consider the following problem, you are tasked with finding the equilibrium price and quantity for a particular good X. 

You are told that the producers are willing and able to sell 2 units for the  price of 16 U.S dollars a unit, and if the price increases, they are able to make 10 units for a price of 20 U.S dollars per unit. Assuming that the supply curve is linear, then it can be modeled by the following equation:

 
The same process can be used to determine the market demand (assuming linearity and that we are given information about the market demand schedule). At a price of 30 U.S dollars consumers are willing to buy 10 units, if the price decreases to 12 U.S dollars, consumers want to buy 20 units. Thus the demand curve corresponds to this equation:

Finally, all we need to do is to set both equations equal to one another and solve for P. Remember, the equilibrium price and quantity are determined by the intersection of the demand and supply curves (note that in the equation below P=Pe).


Now that we have the equilibrium price, we can plug this result in any of our two previous equations representing the market demand and supply curves and solve for Q. They should both  give the quantity demanded when the market is in equilibrium. This is also a nice way to double check your work (i.e if you get two totally different results you probably made a mistake somewhere).

 
Let's visualize that:



In a more realistic fashion, we would say that the market clearing price is 20.91 U.S dollars and the quantity of goods provided is 12 units. It would not make much sense to buy 11 units plus 82% of one good, so we can round that number to 12.

Source: example inspired from Zeder,Raphael.How to Calculate the Equilibrium Price. Quickonomics (2018). 

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Econometrics: Bivariate population model

Hello I'm finally back from my extended break. I thought that we should start studying Econometrics.  Let's begin by analyzing a simple bivariate regression. Assume that this equation describes the relationship between two variables X and Y. We say that Y is the dependent variable, whereas X is the independent variable. In other words, we assume that Y (the output) depends on X (the input). Epsilon is the error term, it represents other factors that affect Y. The error term must be uncorrelated with the variable X so that we do not need to include them in our regression, and thus the coefficient of X (beta) should not change, even though Epsilon also determines Y.  beta-0 is the constant term. It tells us what would be Y if X=0. beta-1 is the effect on Y if X changes by one unit. To see this, assume X=education is a continuous function, let's take the derivative of Y=wage with respect to X: Thus, if education goes up by one unit, we should expect, on average, wage to go up

Macroeconomics: multiplier and crowding out effects

Multiplier effect: whenever   any of the components of AD increases, the increase in GDP will be greater than the initial increase in expenditures. The impact on GDP of a particular increase in spending depends on the proportion of the new income that is taken out of the system to the proportion that continues to circulate in the economy. The multiplier effect tells us the impact a particular change in one the components of AD will have on the total income (GDP).  Let k denote the spending multiplier, which is a function of MPC and MPS. The larger the marginal propensity to consume, the larger the spending multiplier. Notice that the larger the MPC, the greater the impact a particular change in the spending variables will have on the nation's GDP. The crowding out effect: If government spending increases without an increase in taxes, the government must borrow funds from the private sector to finance its deficit, thereby increasing the interest rate. This increase in interest rate,

Econometrics: OLS estimates

  Let X and Y be column vectors and the sample has the size n: The vector beta contains both the coefficient of X as well as the coefficient for the intercept. This is equivalent to writing this equation: We will assume that the expected value of the error term is 0 (this can be done by construction), and that X is uncorrelated to epsilon. Assume the following is for population data. Let's prove that statement: Since we know that the covariance between X and epsilon is 0, it follows that the expected value of X times the error term must also be 0. Since we do not have access to the actual expected value of the distribution, let's use the sample data instead: The hat on the covariance signifies that this is a MM estimator. Let's use the fact that the sample mean of epsilon is also equal to 0, then:   Using the estimation for the covariance and that the expected value of the error term equals 0: Then we have: To get this result, you must use the properties of the summation op