Skip to main content

Microeconomics: perfect competition

Perfect competition happens when both buyers and producers are price takers, meaning they have no (individual) influence over the price of a product.

Conditions for perfect competition:
  1. Large number of producers such that no individual producer's production represents a significant part of the total output in the market. Producers must sell their products (no matter the quantity) at a market price that is outside of their control (price-taker). This means that for firm that is a price-taker, its demand is perfectly elastic (horizontal).
  2. Producers sell homogeneous goods, meaning that consumers do not care from which sellers they buy the goods from.
  3. Producers do not face barriers to entry or exit. Producers are able to enter or exit the market freely.
Understanding economic graphs under perfect competition:


  • The price (Pm) is determined in the market becomes the demand curve for an individual firm (remember the firm is price-taker). Then, if the demand is horizontal, it follows by the product rule in calculus, the marginal revenue is constant.

  • Remember, the profit maximizing output is determined by MR=MC.
  • The long run equilibrium is achieved as each individual firm is earning a normal profit (see graph above). If a firm is earning a negative or positive normal profit, firms will exit (enter) the market until a normal profit is achieved at an individual firm level.
  • The firm represented on the graph produces efficiently as it is producing at the lowest point on its average total cost (ATC) curve.

  • An increase in price causes an increase in output. This creates a new marginal revenue equal to the new equilibrium price (Pm2) that is bigger than the original price (Pm1).
  • The firm now produces where Pm2=MR2=MC. At this point, the firm is earning a positive economic profit, in the short run, as Pm2>ATC at the new quantity being produced.
  • Profit is equal to the vertical distance between Pm2 and ATC times the number of goods produced by the firm at that price.
  • The firm is not productively efficient, as it is not s it is producing at the lowest point on its average total cost (ATC) curve.
In the long run, the positive economic profit attracts other firms to enter the market. This new influx of firms will move the supply curve to the right, thereby increasing supply and decreasing the equilibrium price until every firm earns a normal profit.

Should a firm exit the market in the short run if it faces a negative profit? It depends, if the firm is able to cover its variable costs, then it stays in the market. If it cannot cover its variable cost, the firm should exit the market immediately.

The graph on the left indicates that the firm should still operate as it is able to cover its AV costs at that price. However, the firm on the right cannot cover its ATC and has to exit the market.

In the long run, negative economic profit pushes away some firms out of the market, thereby decreasing the supply and increasing the equilibrium price, until every firm earns a normal profit.

Part A of the graph shows that due to a leftward shift in demand (from D1 to D3), the new price Pm3<Pm1. Some firms are experiencing losses and are forced out of the market, reducing supply (S1 to S3). This shift in supply happens up until every firm is making a normal profit which occurs at Pm1.


Reference: Mayer,David. AP Microeconomics Crash Course. Research & Education Association (2014). p 91-99. 




Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Macroeconomics: multiplier and crowding out effects

Multiplier effect: whenever   any of the components of AD increases, the increase in GDP will be greater than the initial increase in expenditures. The impact on GDP of a particular increase in spending depends on the proportion of the new income that is taken out of the system to the proportion that continues to circulate in the economy. The multiplier effect tells us the impact a particular change in one the components of AD will have on the total income (GDP).  Let k denote the spending multiplier, which is a function of MPC and MPS. The larger the marginal propensity to consume, the larger the spending multiplier. Notice that the larger the MPC, the greater the impact a particular change in the spending variables will have on the nation's GDP. The crowding out effect: If government spending increases without an increase in taxes, the government must borrow funds from the private sector to finance its deficit, thereby increasing the interest rate. This increase in interest ...

Exercise: short and long run effects of a fiscal policy

  You are in charge of the government budget for the year 2021. You are told that schools and public roads need to be updated, and you estimate an appropriate budget in order to carry out the task. Describe what will happen in the short run to the economy, and what type of inflation do we see? Describe the supply side effect from this policy, explain what happens in the long run. Assume that there is no crowding out effect. First, note that updating public infractures, assuming taxes stay the same, will require an increase in government spending, which will also have an impact on the investment and consumption level in the economy (remember the spending multiplier?). Therefore, the aggregate demand curve will shift to the right. This will cause inflation (i.e positive change in the price level) and a higher output in the short-run.  Note that if we were to assume a large crowding out effect, the short run aggregate supply curve would shift to the left (increase in production c...

Exercise: maximizing profit

Assume that you are the owner of a small business that produces T-shirts. Your the total revenue for your business can be modeled by the following equation: and your total cost corresponds to this function: Find the point at which your firm maximizes its profit. Then, find how much profit the firm if able to earn at that point. Using the total cost and total revenue functions we can set up the profit function: Then, realize that if you want to find the maximum profit, take the derivative of the function and set it up equal to zero, and solve for Q. This is equivalent of taking the derivative of the total cost and total revenue functions and setting them equal to each other. In this problem, I chose the latter option as it was explained in the previous lessons. Notice that profit is often denoted by a capital pi.  We are assuming that the TR>TC for some positive value, you can check for yourself. However, if we did not know that, we would first take the first ...