Skip to main content

Microeconomics: monopolistic competition

Monopolistic Competition:

It is a market structure that has similarities with both perfect competition and monopoly.

  • Similarities with perfect competition:
    • There are multiple firms competing against each other. One common example is fast food chain restaurants.
    • Low barriers to entry. Therefore a firm can easily enter a monopolistic competitive market.   
    • In the short run, firms can earn an economic profit. In the long run, the economic profit attracts other firms up until the economic profit disappear. 
  • Similarities with monopoly:
    • Monopolistic competitive firms have the ability to set a price for their products, though changing prices affects quantity sold proportionally more than for a monopolist.
    • Each firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve due to their pricing power, but it is more elastic (i.e flatter) than for a monopolist.
    • Since each firm faces a downward-sloping demand, the marginal revenue is less than demand.
  •  Unique features:
    • In order to earn an economic profit, each firm produces a different products from their competitors. A firm's effort to differentiate its product from other firms is called product differentiation.
    • Firms spend some of their resources on advertising their products. This is done in order to create brand loyalty push the idea that their products is different than the products produced by their competitors.
Monopolistic competition in the short-run:

  • product differentiation allows a monopolistically competitive firm to earn an economic profit in the short run.
  • Product differentiation causes a firm's demand and marginal revenue to be downward sloping.
  • Firms maximize profit when producing at the quantity where the marginal revenue equals marginal cost.
  • Monopolistically competitive firms are inefficient in the short run:
    • Productively inefficient as the quantity produce is not on the lowest point of the average total cost curve.
    • Allocatively inefficient since the price earned is not equal to the marginal cost. Thus creating a dead-weight loss in the market.


Monopolistic competition in the long run:


  • As long as P>ATC (i.e positive profit), more firms want to enter the market and compete.
  • As new firms enter the market, demand for existing firm's product decreasing (demand shifts left) until no firms earn a positive economic profit.
  • Unlike in perfect competition, the long run equilibrium is neither productively or allocativelly efficient.
  • Monopolistically-competitive firms do not produce at the lowest point of the ATC. The difference between  the output at the lowest point on the ATC curve and the long run equilibrium output is called excess capacity.


References: 

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Macroeconomics: multiplier and crowding out effects

Multiplier effect: whenever   any of the components of AD increases, the increase in GDP will be greater than the initial increase in expenditures. The impact on GDP of a particular increase in spending depends on the proportion of the new income that is taken out of the system to the proportion that continues to circulate in the economy. The multiplier effect tells us the impact a particular change in one the components of AD will have on the total income (GDP).  Let k denote the spending multiplier, which is a function of MPC and MPS. The larger the marginal propensity to consume, the larger the spending multiplier. Notice that the larger the MPC, the greater the impact a particular change in the spending variables will have on the nation's GDP. The crowding out effect: If government spending increases without an increase in taxes, the government must borrow funds from the private sector to finance its deficit, thereby increasing the interest rate. This increase in interest ...

Exercise: maximizing profit

Assume that you are the owner of a small business that produces T-shirts. Your the total revenue for your business can be modeled by the following equation: and your total cost corresponds to this function: Find the point at which your firm maximizes its profit. Then, find how much profit the firm if able to earn at that point. Using the total cost and total revenue functions we can set up the profit function: Then, realize that if you want to find the maximum profit, take the derivative of the function and set it up equal to zero, and solve for Q. This is equivalent of taking the derivative of the total cost and total revenue functions and setting them equal to each other. In this problem, I chose the latter option as it was explained in the previous lessons. Notice that profit is often denoted by a capital pi.  We are assuming that the TR>TC for some positive value, you can check for yourself. However, if we did not know that, we would first take the first ...

A short interlude...

Hello all, it's been quite some time since I have made any major announcements since the creation of this blog about a year and a half ago. I am currently in graduate school and will soon take a portion of my comprehensive examination (i.e exams in Micro, Macro, and Metrics that will allow me to continue my studies in my graduate program), wish me luck! Thus, I will not be able to post consistently until at least mid-June. The roadmap is as such, if I pass, I will start introductory lessons in Econometrics and Statistics (if not, then I'll have to study until I can retake the comps in August). I hope that once I am done, I will be able to add more advance materials to the blog, such as general equilibrium, indirect utility functions, and game theory/mechanism design for Micro. The Solow, Ramsey, RBC, New Keynesian models, permanent income hypothesis (PIH) and more for Macro. By the way I think I still need to add notes on the IS-LM curves, so I will do that before jumping to t...