Skip to main content

Microeconomics: competitive factor markets and monopsony

Perfectly-competitive factor markets:

  • A competitive factor market is a market in which a large amount of firms are looking to hire similar workers. Due to the numerous firms in the market, each firm's hiring decision does not influence the market wage rate. These firms are referred to as wage-takers.
  • The market wage (w) is determined by the equilibrium of the supply and demand curve for labor (see the graph below). The market labor demand is the summation of all the firms' MRP's at each quantity, and the market supply curve is determined by the workers' willingness to provide more labor at higher wage rates. 
  • For a competitive firm, the market wage is the firm's marginal factor cost (MFC) and the supply curve (S) it faces. Supply equals marginal factor cost because wage is constant. The firm hires the quantity that is equal to the intersection between its MRP and w.




Monospony in the factor market:

  • A monospony occurs when there is only a single buyer in a market.
  • If there is a monospony in a factor market, this means that there is a single employer for labor or capital. If a town has one large factory that employs unskilled worker, this is a good approximation for a monopsony.
  • In a monopsony, the marginal factor cost is different from the labor supply curve. The marginal cost is increasing at a faster rate.
  • The result of a monopsony in a factor market is a lower price for the factors of production and a smaller quantity of factors used.

  • You can see that compared with the competitive market in the first graph, the wage set by the monopsony (w') is smaller than the wage rate in a competitive market (w). Furthermore the quantity of factors used is also smaller.
Reference: Mayer,David. AP Microeconomics Crash Course. Research & Education Association (2014). p 128-131.


Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Econometrics: Bivariate population model

Hello I'm finally back from my extended break. I thought that we should start studying Econometrics.  Let's begin by analyzing a simple bivariate regression. Assume that this equation describes the relationship between two variables X and Y. We say that Y is the dependent variable, whereas X is the independent variable. In other words, we assume that Y (the output) depends on X (the input). Epsilon is the error term, it represents other factors that affect Y. The error term must be uncorrelated with the variable X so that we do not need to include them in our regression, and thus the coefficient of X (beta) should not change, even though Epsilon also determines Y.  beta-0 is the constant term. It tells us what would be Y if X=0. beta-1 is the effect on Y if X changes by one unit. To see this, assume X=education is a continuous function, let's take the derivative of Y=wage with respect to X: Thus, if education goes up by one unit, we should expect, on average, wage to go up

Macroeconomics: multiplier and crowding out effects

Multiplier effect: whenever   any of the components of AD increases, the increase in GDP will be greater than the initial increase in expenditures. The impact on GDP of a particular increase in spending depends on the proportion of the new income that is taken out of the system to the proportion that continues to circulate in the economy. The multiplier effect tells us the impact a particular change in one the components of AD will have on the total income (GDP).  Let k denote the spending multiplier, which is a function of MPC and MPS. The larger the marginal propensity to consume, the larger the spending multiplier. Notice that the larger the MPC, the greater the impact a particular change in the spending variables will have on the nation's GDP. The crowding out effect: If government spending increases without an increase in taxes, the government must borrow funds from the private sector to finance its deficit, thereby increasing the interest rate. This increase in interest rate,

Econometrics: OLS estimates

  Let X and Y be column vectors and the sample has the size n: The vector beta contains both the coefficient of X as well as the coefficient for the intercept. This is equivalent to writing this equation: We will assume that the expected value of the error term is 0 (this can be done by construction), and that X is uncorrelated to epsilon. Assume the following is for population data. Let's prove that statement: Since we know that the covariance between X and epsilon is 0, it follows that the expected value of X times the error term must also be 0. Since we do not have access to the actual expected value of the distribution, let's use the sample data instead: The hat on the covariance signifies that this is a MM estimator. Let's use the fact that the sample mean of epsilon is also equal to 0, then:   Using the estimation for the covariance and that the expected value of the error term equals 0: Then we have: To get this result, you must use the properties of the summation op